Furry Brown Dog

Dedicated to the memory of my canine friend…

Archive for the ‘Economics and business’ Category

What explains Singapore’s persistently low crime rate?

with 13 comments

Why does Singapore have one of the lowest crime rates in the world? What is responsible for such a phenomena? Of course the usual PAP establishment apologists attribute this to the government’s policies on crime, which they argued have kept Singapore as one of the safest cities in the world. But is there all there is to it? How exactly did the PAP do it?

Let us first examine the trend of overall crime decline. Looking at old articles, the crime rate began falling in 1989 as stated in this 1991 ST article:

Senior Assistant Commissioner Khoo Boon Hui said yesterday: “The decline in the overall crime this year is particularly heartening as it indicates that the police have successfully sustained the falling crime trend of the past 2 1/2 years.”

Indeed a 1989 ST news article first records the beginning of this trend. From 1992 to 2011, Singapore’s crime rate has seen a continuous decline as follows:

What could account for such a steady drop in committed crimes? Kishore Mahbubani, a Lee Kuan Yew School of Public Policy professor attributed it to policies such as the high level of trust between the public and police, tough laws, economic growth and development as well universal education. But is that all?

Read the rest of this entry »

Written by defennder

May 10, 2012 at 5:11 PM

Why Singapore’s stellar GDP per capita figures are unimpressive in context

with 6 comments

Update: Amended the title just to be more specific with the content of the article.

Some time ago I wrote this post explaining why I felt that Singapore’s high GDP per capita ranking is unexceptional when put into context. It’s still worth a read. The main gist of the argument (more specifically the 2nd point) is that Singapore’s GDP per capita  when compared to numerous other cities does not rank amongst the top in the world. The obsession with GDP per capita, is understood to have reached fever pitch when Singapore was judged to have reached a Swiss standard of living simply by attaining a comparable GNP per capita with Switzerland’s in 1999. For example, Matt Miller of the Washington Post gushed over Singapore’s GDP per capita in a recent op-ed here.

A recent publication by an American think tank seems to support this argument. The report argues that the US is more economically developed than much of Europe simply because more of their population is packed into mega-cities:

The United States, it turns out, actually derives more economic benefit from its cities than any other country on the planet. Roughly 83 percent of America’s GDP came from its “large cities,” defined as cities with a population of 150,000 or more. By contrast, China got 78 percent of its GDP from large cities and Western Europe got a surprisingly small 65 percent of its GDP from its large urban areas. Here’s the chart:

The report’s authors argue that the city gap between the United States and Europe account for about three-quarters of the difference in per capita GDP between the two. In other words, the United States appears to be wealthier than Europe because it has a greater share of its population living in large, productive cities.

All told, some 80 percent of Americans live in large cities, versus just 58 percent of Western Europeans.

In any case, the report also notes that America’s largest cities will continue to play an outsized role in the global economy. In 2025, the report predicts, about 600 cities around the globe will account for 60 percent of the world’s GDP.

So what does this tell us? It means that if a country has more cities and a larger proportion of its people residing or packed in mega-cities, it is expected that the country would enjoy stronger economic growth. Taken to extremes, what happens if your country consists of just one mega-city (ie. a city-state)? The answer is that you would enjoy stellar high GDP per capita figures.

Read the rest of this entry »

Written by defennder

May 10, 2012 at 12:00 AM

Tharman’s remarks in the context of the evolving foreign talent policy

with 4 comments

Recently, Finance Minister Tharman stirred up a ruckus when he defended the foreign talent scheme by citing how Taiwanese wages had flattened over the last decade due to its closed door policy. Popular blogger Lucky Tan rebutted Tharman here and here, primarily by turning Tharman’s argument on its head: Tharman essentially put the cart before the horse; the reason why Taiwan’s not attracting foreign talent is precisely because of stagnant wages which had flatlined over the past ten years, not the other way round.

This point is echoed by Taiwan’s deputy Labour minister:

It is not the government’s policies that have led to the brain drain, but Taiwan’s “comparatively low wage levels,” which have failed to retain local talent or attract professionals from overseas, Pan said.

While the average starting pay for new graduates in Taiwan is between NT$20,000 and NT$30,000, “a Taiwanese college graduate may earn NT$50,000, NT$60,000 or even NT$70,000 if they work in Singapore,” he said.

“The problem lies with enterprises who are unwilling to raise salaries for their staff members,” Pan said.

Read the rest of this entry »

Written by defennder

April 11, 2012 at 12:41 AM

The riddle of GIC’s performance and CPF funds

with 20 comments

Ok let’s try to talk about something other than Dr Patrick Tan’s national service. GIC released its annual report last week. Unlike most investment funds, GIC doesn’t provide year-on-year performances. It reports its performance in the form of a rolling annualised 20 year rate of return in USD. So there’s no way to know, unlike for Temasek Holdings, how much GIC lost or made in a single year. So we make do with what we have.

Now most people, including myself is under the impression that CPF monies are managed by GIC which invests them overseas. Call this the CPF-GIC model. I recall reading a book by Rodney King, The Singapore Miracle which says that GIC is barred from investing in the domestic market because it is feared that its large size may destabilise the markets with its investment moves. True or not, I’ve no idea. But what’s particularly interesting is GIC’s performance as reported.

Read the rest of this entry »

Written by defennder

August 4, 2011 at 8:21 PM

3-cornered electoral fights and Arrow’s impossibility theorem

with 2 comments

Recently Alex Au wrote a couple of posts here and here questioning if opposition parties’ attempt to avoid 3-cornered fights might be undemocratic to voters since they offer the electorate fewer choices. Now of course this might appear to most people as a stupid conclusion to reach. There are many reasons to believe that doing so would help only the PAP, but this post would not attempt to go down that line. Lucky has done so here and has E-Jay here. To begin let’s start by quoting Alex’s argument that having more opposition parties contest in the same district would result in a more democratic outcome:

But this logic is based on an assumption which, strangely, no one has yet interrogated: that there is a relatively inelastic pool of voters who would not want to vote for the PAP and that they would vote for whichever opposition party happened to be standing in their constituency. You see this assumption at work whenever someone talks about not “splitting” the vote.

From what I have seen, opposition parties are not interchangeable, and even if there are days when one is frustrated with the PAP, not all of the other parties are always preferable to the PAP.

But the trend to differentiate themselves by articulating convictions and policy directions can only mean that they will become less and less interchangeable. I may like Party K and Party L for their positions; I may not like Party M and Party N. So, come election time, why should I be denied the opportunity to choose among K, L, M and N?

However, it is not necessary to argue as E-Jay did, that 3-cornered fights can only be considered a more democratic electoral representation if Singapore were more democratic. Something known as Arrow’s impossibility theorem proves that result does not hold mathematically regardless of that setting. In other words, 3-cornered fights are undemocratic and unfair purely from a rigorous and mathematical point of view. I will attempt to argue that offering the electorate more choices may paradoxically result in a less fair and undemocratic outcome from a strictly theoretical perspective, without taking into account Singapore’s electoral history and landscape. Similarly the argument that having one opposition party give in the does not necessarily imply that the move was done purely out of a motive to deny the PAP their votes without any consideration whether doing so might actually result in an electoral outcome which is more reflective of the electorate’s ranking preference.

Read the rest of this entry »

Written by defennder

March 22, 2011 at 7:59 PM

A comparative analysis of real CPF returns and other provident funds

with 18 comments

“If that is the case…does the Government short-change Singaporeans by giving CPF members 3.5 per cent of the interest rate while the GIC makes 9 per cent (and) pockets the balance of 5.5 per cent?” -Worker’s Party Secretary-General Low Thia Khiang, parliamentary session on 18th Sept 2007.

“Sir, the poor rate of returns on CPF balances is one of the main reasons why the existing CPF scheme, without reform, will be inadequate to meet Singaporeans’ retirement needs. As a long-term retirement savings plan, the CPF’s rate of return is crucial. Unfortunately, the rate of return enjoyed by CPF members has been poor.” – Then-NMP Siew Kum Hong, parliamentary session 18th Sept 2007.

“You can’t completely guarantee this system that you are providing now. This is because there isn’t any risk-free asset that can be certain to achieve the 2.5 per annum minimum return.” – Then-Manpower Minister Ng Eng Hen in reply to Low and Siew.

How does the Singapore’s CPF rate of return measure up against those of similar pension funds of other countries? This was a question which I sought to answer back in 2009. Back then I promised readers (mostly consisting of myself) that I would update the post with real returns of other provident funds instead of mere nominal figures. I barely found time (and motivation, it’s a lot of work to source for and dig up data) to do so only until somewhat recently. While nominal CPF returns may appear comparatively low, Singapore’s low inflation rate (disregarding issues of whether inflation is adequately measured in Singapore) leaves open the possibility that CPF provides a better real rate of return as compared that of other countries.

Notes: This post may be considered an update of the older 2009 one, but much of its contents will be plagiarised; there’s no need to read the earlier 2009 post if you’re reading this one.

Singapore’s CPF earns the dubious honour for having the highest mandatory contribution rate (thus robbing its depositors the most of their take-home pay) and providing the lowest return (annual interest accrued where relevant). For this article, I examined four listed countries’ provident funds in Wikipedia, namely Singapore, India, Hong Kong and Malaysia. There may well be more provident funds, but for some reason Wikipedia only has four listed. These four schemes would be examined in detail below.

Read the rest of this entry »

Written by defennder

March 19, 2011 at 12:35 AM

Tharman’s $3100 real median income target: Back to the future?

with 2 comments

Singapore Budget 2011 was just released Friday. I have yet to look through all the documents, only focussing on the main highlights on the Singapore Budget 2011 website. At a quick glance much of it looks likes the standard pre-election handout, which Singaporean voters saw in 2001 as New Singapore Shares (NSS) or its 2006 successor Progress Package. Predictably both were given a few months before the General Elections.

One long-term Budget goal in particular caught my attention. It wasn’t a new Budget or economic growth target. It was instead a re-affirmation of a long term economic goal which was first articulated by Finance Minister Tharman back in July 2010. Back then Tharman said that it was tied to the government’s earlier announcement back in Feb 2010 of boosting Singapore’s lackluster productivity by about 2-3% annually over the next decade.

Citing current median wages of $2400, Tharman said that it was the government’s goal to bring that up to $3100 (30% increase) in real terms over the next 10 years. Naturally, such a proposal generated a lot of skepticism amongst Singapore netizens, some of whom claimed that the government would simply reach into its bag of tricks and pull in wealthy immigrants in order to bring up the median income instead of restructuring the economy or establishing social safety nets to do so. Yet for many others, this represented a change from vague promises such as promising to achieve Swiss standards of living, and as mentioned earlier was nothing more than a veiled GDP per capita growth target.

Read the rest of this entry »

Written by defennder

February 20, 2011 at 4:06 PM

Follow

Get every new post delivered to your Inbox.

Join 42 other followers